Contenu de l'article

Titre Une augmentation de la productivité par réduction des effectifs dans les principaux pays de l'Ocdé : conséquences d'après le modèle Atlas
Auteur Didier Miqueu, François Cellier, Dominique Bureau
Mir@bel Revue Economie et prévision
Numéro no 69, 1985/3
Page 29-51
Résumé anglais Increasing productivity through labour cut-backs in the major Oecd countries : study of the consequences using the Atlas model, by Dominique Bureau, François Cellier, Didier Miqueu. Seeking to improve productivity appears to be an increasingly frequent aim of economic policymakers and also a long term means of increasing employment by improving competitivity. Different simulations were carried out using the Atlas model, on the one hand to quantify these mechanisms when one country attempts on its own to increase its productivity, and on the other hand to study the results when several countries at once attempt to increase their productivity in this way, mutually neutralizing their efforts. The increase in productivity is obtained in this simulation by reducing manpower in a given year. So we have to analyse the macroeconomic effects of a supply policy rather than one of improving productivity by stimulating demand, the "supply side" also being characterized by the important role played in investment dynamics by reconstitution of profits. When a single country reduces its workforce by 1 %, inflation in that country goes down in the short term by 0.5% on average in the first year and 1.3% the third year. Its competitivity improves, pushing its exports up by some 0.6% after 3 years Its gross domestic product, however, shrinks at first, by 0.4% on average in the first year, because of the fall in income catrsed by the staff lay-offs. Then the gross domestic product recovers and just about overtakes its base value after three years. In the long term, countries develop differently according to whether the initial productivity supplement is wholly or only partially reflected in wages. In the first case, prices and productivity more or less even out at their initial levels In the second case, they differ from base levels, with gross domestic product gaining about 0.5% on average after seven years. Be that as it may, employment remains below the base level by 0.6% on average in the seventh year. When all countries simultaneously follow a productivity policy in search of increased competitivity, production is depressed in the short term, the gross domestic product of the Oecd zone falling off by 0.7% in the first year and only regaining its initial level after three years. But it is worth noting that in the long term the gross domestic product of the zone rises some 0.5% above its initial level, which is comparable to the average figure for any single country trying to increase its competitivity by reducing its labour force. Since the increase in competitivity is usually zero when all countries take action together, this increase in production and rncome can only be explained by the international market forces boosting disinflation. The drop in consumer prices in the Oecd stands at 0.60% the first year, 1.7% the third year and 2.4% after seven years. In this simulation of productivity policy the Oecd also benefits from a 0.5% improvement in volume of its net exports, setting off a similar decrease in its terms of trade reflecting the fact that the prices of petroleum and raw materials are considered to remain constant whilst the prices of manufactured goods go down. A change of hypothesis on this point, loss-adjusting the prices of raw materials for example, would not change the actual pattern of long term development of production but only the weighting of its determinants. In conclusion, whereas one might have expected a policy of productivity through labour cut-backs to be effective only when carried out by one single country, it would seem that when several countries simultaneously practice such a policy the long term results are the same because of disinflation, even if the advantages of relative competitivity are lost. Hence there is no significant loss of efficiency, but these policies are not necessarily efficient, since the new jobs they create in the long run are not sufficient to provide work for all those who were laid off at the outset. Of the 1% of jobs lost in the first year 0.6% will still not have been replaced by new jobs seven. years later.
Source : Éditeur (via Persée)
Article en ligne http://www.persee.fr/web/revues/home/prescript/article/ecop_0249-4744_1985_num_69_3_3401